The
Economics Nobel: Giving Adam Smith a Helping Hand
By Adrian Cho
ScienceNOW Daily News
15 October 2007
Scottish
philosopher Adam Smith asserted that when everyone acts out of self-interest,
everyone will eventually benefit, as if a benevolent "invisible
hand" molds the economy. Economists now know that view is naive:
They can prove that in some situations, rational people will act in
ways that leave everybody a loser. But such dreary outcomes can sometimes
be avoided, thanks to work that today earned three Americans the Nobel
Prize in economics.
Leonid Hurwicz of the University of Minnesota, Twin Cities, Erik Maskin
of the Institute for Advanced Study in Princeton, New Jersey, and Roger
Myerson of the University of Chicago, Illinois, developed "mechanism
design theory." Such study aims to find schemes, or "mechanisms,"
that ensure that acting in self-interest will indeed lead to benefits
for all. Today, the theory's applications range from how best to auction
broadcast rights and other public resources to contract negotiations
and elections.
"I
was surprised. At first, I thought it was some kind of a joke,"
says Hurwicz, of hearing of his award. At 90, Hurwicz is the oldest
person to win a Nobel. He says colleagues had told him that he might
win, "but not in recent years." The prize is well-deserved,
others say. "I was riding in the car [and discussing the prize]
with somebody yesterday, and these were the three names that came up,"
says W. Bentley MacLeod, an economist at Columbia University.
Mechanism
design theory starts with the recognition that unbridled self-interest
doesn't always lead to the greater good. For example, suppose the people
of a town would benefit if they built a bridge across the river. Everyone
is asked to estimate how much the bridge is worth to him personally
and chip in accordingly. Rationally, each person benefits by underestimating
his stake in the bridge and letting others bear the cost. So for lack
of funds the bridge never gets built, and the whole community suffers.
This lose-lose situation is known as a Nash equilibrium, and it's logically
unavoidable because an individual can only make his own situation worse
by paying more.
In the
1960s, Hurwicz pioneered the study of how to avoid such dead ends by
fiddling with the rules of such an economic interaction. The trick is
to fix things so that the most beneficial state and the inevitable result,
or equilibrium state, are one and the same. "It's a little Machiavellian,"
says Gabrielle Demange of the Paris School of Economics. "Given
a goal, you design a game so that in the end the Nash equilibrium comes
out to be what you want." For example, in the case of the bridge,
the amount each person pays could be based on only what others think
the bridge should be worth, thus eliminating each person's incentive
to lie about its value.
Maskin,
57, and Myerson, 56, expanded on Hurwicz's work. For example, in 1977,
Maskin developed a criterion for determining just when it's possible
to find a set of rules that will guide self-interested participants
to the desired end. "This sets some boundaries on what mechanism
design theory can do," says Massimo Morelli, an economist at Columbia.
Starting in the late 1970s, Myerson showed that whenever a mechanism
exists, it is also possible to find one that gives participants an incentive
to tell the truth.
Relying
heavily on game theory, the laureates' work has been largely abstract
and formal. "My methodology is to invent simple little worlds in
which there is just a bit that we don't understand and can study,"
Myerson says. Nevertheless, the theory may play a role in confronting
perhaps the most complex and pressing problem facing humanity today,
climate change, by helping to set up incentives that encourage consumers
and countries to minimize greenhouse gas emissions. But first, politicians
must identify the specific end they are working toward, Maskin says.
"Mechanism design should definitely be pertinent to the problem,"
he says, "but first we have to decide exactly what we're trying
to accomplish."